CHAPTER ONE
Late Victorian Holocausts
El
Niρo Famines and the Making of the Third World
By MIKE DAVIS
Verso
Read
the Review
Victoria's Ghosts
The more one hears about this famine, the more one feels
that such a hideous record of human suffering and destruction the
world has never seen before.
Florence Nightingale,
1877
"Here's the northeast monsoon at last," said Hon. Robert Ellis,
C.B., junior member of the Governor's Council, Madras, as a heavy
shower of rain fell at Coonoor, on a day towards the end of October
1876, when the members of the Madras Government were returning from
their summer sojourn on the hills.
"I am afraid that is not the monsoon," said the
gentleman to whom the remark was made.
"Not the monsoon?" rejoined Mr. Ellis. "Good
God! It must be the monsoon. If it is not, and if the monsoon does not
come, there will be an awful famine."
The British rulers of Madras had every reason to be apprehensive.
The life-giving southwest monsoon had already failed much of southern
and central India the previous summer. The Madras Observatory would
record only 6.3 inches of precipitation for all of 1876 in contrast to
the annual average of 27.6 inches during the previous decade. The fate
of millions now hung on the timely arrival of generous winter rains.
Despite Ellis's warning, the governor of Madras, Richard Grenville,
the Duke of Buckingham and Chandos, who was a greenhorn to India and
its discontents, sailed away on a leisurely tour of the Andaman
Islands, Burma and Ceylon. When he finally reached Colombo, he found
urgent cables detailing the grain riots sweeping the so-called Ceded
Districts of Kurnool, Cuddapah and Bellary in the wake of another
monsoon failure. Popular outbursts against impossibly high prices were
likewise occurring in the Deccan districts of the neighboring Bombay
Presidency, especially in Ahmednagar and Sholapur. Having tried to
survive on roots while awaiting the rains, multitudes of peasants and
laborers were now on the move, fleeing a slowly dying countryside.
As the old-hands at Fort St. George undoubtedly
realized, the semi-arid interior of India was primed for disaster. The
worsening depression in world trade had been spreading misery and
igniting discontent throughout cotton-exporting districts of the
Deccan, where in any case forest enclosures and the displacement of
gram by cotton had greatly reduced local food security. The
traditional system of household and village grain reserves regulated
by complex networks of patrimonial obligation had been largely
supplanted since the Mutiny by merchant inventories and the cash
nexus. Although rice and wheat production in the rest of India (which
now included bonanzas of coarse rice from the recently conquered
Irrawaddy delta) had been above average for the past three years, much
of the surplus had been exported to England. Londoners were in effect
eating India's bread. "It seems an anomaly," wrote a troubled
observer, "that, with her famines on hand, India is able to supply
food for other parts of the world."
There were other "anomalies." The newly
constructed railroads, lauded as institutional safeguards against
famine, were instead used by merchants to ship grain inventories from
outlying drought-stricken districts to central depots for hoarding (as
well as protection from rioters). Likewise the telegraph ensured that
price hikes were coordinated in a thousand towns at once, regardless
of local supply trends. Moreover, British antipathy to price control
invited anyone who had the money to join in the frenzy of grain
speculation. "Besides regular traders," a British official reported
from Meerut in late 1876, "men of all sorts embarked in it who had or
could raise any capital; jewelers and cloth dealers pledging their
stocks, even their wives' jewels, to engage in business and import
grain." Buckingham, not a free-trade fundamentalist, was appalled by
the speed with which modern markets accelerated rather than relieved
the famine:
The rise [of prices] was so extraordinary, and the
available supply, as compared with well-known requirements, so
scanty that merchants and dealers, hopeful of enormous future gains,
appeared determined to hold their stocks for some indefinite time
and not to part with the article which was becoming of such unwonted
value. It was apparent to the Government that facilities for moving
grain by the rail were rapidly raising prices everywhere, and that
the activity of apparent importation and railway transit, did not
indicate any addition to the food stocks of the Presidency ...
retail trade up-country was almost at standstill. Either prices were
asked which were beyond the means of the multitude to pay, or shops
remained entirely closed.
As a result, food prices soared out of the reach
of outcaste labourers, displaced weavers, sharecroppers and poor
peasants. "The dearth," as The Nineteenth Century pointed out a
few months later, "was one of money and of labour rather than of
food." The earlier optimism of mid-Victorian observers Karl Marx as
well as Lord Salisbury about the velocity of economic transformation
in India, especially the railroad revolution, had failed to adequately
discount for the fiscal impact of such "modernization." The taxes that
financed the railroads had also crushed the ryots. Their inability to
purchase subsistence was further compounded by the depreciation of the
rupee due to the new international Gold Standard (which India had not
adopted), which steeply raised the cost of imports. Thanks to the
price explosion, the poor began to starve to death even in
well-watered districts like Thanjavur in Tamil Nadu, "reputed to be
immune to food shortages." Sepoys meanwhile encountered increasing
difficulty in enforcing order in the panic-stricken bazaars and
villages as famine engulfed the vast Deccan plateau. Roadblocks were
hastily established to stem the flood of stick-thin country people
into Bombay and Poona, while in Madras the police forcibly expelled
some 25,000 famine refugees.
India's Nero
The central government under the leadership of Queen Victoria's
favorite poet, Lord Lytton, vehemently opposed efforts by Buckingham
and some of his district officers to stockpile grain or otherwise
interfere with market forces. All through the autumn of 1876, while
the vital kharif crop was withering in the fields of southern
India, Lytton had been absorbed in organizing the immense Imperial
Assemblage in Delhi to proclaim Victoria Empress of India
(Kaiser-i-Hind). As The Times's special correspondent described
it, "The Viceroy seemed to have made the tales of Arabian fiction true
... nothing was too rich, nothing too costly." "Lytton put on a
spectacle," adds a biographer of Lord Salisbury (the secretary of
state for India), "which achieved the two criteria Salisbury had set
him six months earlier, of being `gaudy enough to impress the
orientals' ... and furthermore a pageant which hid `the nakedness of
the sword on which we really rely.'" Its "climacteric ceremonial"
included a week-long feast for 68,000 officials, satraps and
maharajas: the most colossal and expensive meal in world history. An
English journalist later estimated that 100,000 of the Queen-Empress's
subjects starved to death in Madras and Mysore in the course of
Lytton's spectacular durbar. Indians in future generations
justifiably would remember him as their Nero.
Following this triumph, the viceroy seemed to
regard the growing famine as a tiresome distraction from the Great
Game of preempting Russia in Central Asia by fomenting war with the
blameless Sher Ali, the Emir of Afghanistan. Lytton, according to
Salisbury, was "burning with anxiety to distinguish himself in a great
war." Serendipitously for him, the Czar was on a collision course with
Turkey in the Balkans, and Disraeli and Salisbury were eager to show
the Union Jack on the Khyber Pass. Lytton's warrant, as he was
constantly reminded by his chief budgetary adviser, Sir John Strachey,
was to ensure that Indian, not English, taxpayers paid the costs of
what Radical critics later denounced as "a war of deliberately planned
aggression." The depreciation of the rupee made strict parsimony in
the non-military budget even more urgent.
The 44-year-old Lytton, the former minister to
Lisbon, had replaced the Earl of Northbrook after the latter had
honorably refused to acquiesce in Disraeli's machiavellian "forward"
policy on the northwest frontier. He was a strange and troubling
choice (actually, only fourth on Salisbury's short list) to exercise
paramount authority over a starving subcontinent of 250 million
people. A writer, seemingly admired only by Victoria, who wrote "vast,
stale poems" and ponderous novels under the nom de plume of
Owen Meredith, he had been accused of plagiarism by both Swinburne and
his own father, Bulwer-Lytton (author of The Last Days of
Pompeii). Moreover, it was widely suspected that the new viceroy's
judgement was addled by opium and incipient insanity. Since a nervous
breakdown in 1868, Lytton had repeatedly exhibited wild swings between
megalomania and self-lacerating despair.
Although his possible psychosis ("Lytton's mind
tends violently to exaggeration" complained Salisbury to Disraeli) was
allowed free rein over famine policy, it became a cabinet scandal
after he denounced his own government in October 1877 for "allegedly
attempting to create an Anglo-Franco-Russian coalition against
Germany." As one of Salisbury's biographers has emphasized, this was
"about as absurd a contention as it was possible to make at the time,
even from the distance of Simla," and it produced an explosion inside
Whitehall. "Salisbury explained the Viceroy's ravings by admitting
that he was `a little mad'. It was known that both Lytton and his
father had used opium, and when Derby read the `inconceivable'
memorandum, he concluded that Lytton was dangerous and should resign:
`When a man inherits insanity from one parent, and limitless conceit
from the other, he has a ready-made excuse for almost any extravagance
which he may commit.'"
But in adopting a strict laissez-faire approach
to famine, Lytton, demented or not, could claim to be extravagance's
greatest enemy. He clearly conceived himself to be standing on the
shoulders of giants, or, at least, the sacerdotal authority of Adam
Smith, who a century earlier in The Wealth of Nations had
asserted (vis-ΰ-vis the terrible Bengal drought-famine of 1770)
that "famine has never arisen from any other cause but the violence of
government attempting, by improper means, to remedy the inconvenience
of dearth." Smith's injunction against state attempts to regulate the
price of grain during famine had been taught for years in the East
India Company's famous college at Haileybury. Thus the viceroy was
only repeating orthodox curriculum when he lectured Buckingham that
high prices, by stimulating imports and limiting consumption, were the
"natural saviours of the situation." He issued strict,
"semi-theological" orders that "there is to be no interference of any
kind on the part of Government with the object of reducing the price
of food," and "in his letters home to the India Office and to
politicians of both parties, he denounced `humanitarian hysterics'."
"Let the British public foot the bill for its `cheap sentiment,' if it
wished to save life at a cost that would bankrupt India." By official
dictate, India like Ireland before it had become a Utilitarian
laboratory where millions of lives were wagered against dogmatic faith
in omnipotent markets overcoming the "inconvenience of dearth." Grain
merchants, in fact, preferred to export a record 6.4 million cwt. of
wheat to Europe in 1877-78 rather than relieve starvation in India.
Lytton, to be fair, probably believed that he
was in any case balancing budgets against lives that were already
doomed or devalued of any civilized human quality. The grim doctrines
of Thomas Malthus, former Chair of Political Economy at Haileybury,
still held great sway over the white rajas. Although it was bad
manners to openly air such opinions in front of the natives in
Calcutta, Malthusian principles, updated by Social Darwinism, were
regularly invoked to legitimize Indian famine policy at home in
England. Lytton, who justified his stringencies to the Legislative
Council in 1877 by arguing that the Indian population "has a tendency
to increase more rapidly than the food it raises from the soil," most
likely subscribed to the melancholy viewpoint expressed by Sir Evelyn
Baring (afterwards Lord Cromer), the finance minister, in a later
debate on the government's conduct during the 1876-79 catastrophe.
"[E]very benevolent attempt made to mitigate the effects of famine and
defective sanitation serves but to enhance the evils resulting from
overpopulation." In the same vein, an 1881 report "concluded that 80%
of the famine mortality were drawn from the poorest 20% of the
population, and if such deaths were prevented this stratum of the
population would still be unable to adopt prudential restraint. Thus,
if the government spent more of its revenue on famine relief, an even
larger proportion of the population would become penurious." As in
Ireland thirty years before, those with the power to relieve famine
convinced themselves that overly heroic exertions against implacable
natural laws, whether of market prices or population growth, were
worse than no effort at all.
His recent biographers claim that Salisbury, the
gray eminence of Indian policy, was privately tormented by these
Malthusian calculations. A decade earlier, during his first stint as
secretary of state for India, he had followed the advice of the
Council in Calcutta and refused to intervene in the early stages of a
deadly famine in Orissa. "I did nothing for two months," he later
confessed. "Before that time the monsoon had closed the ports of
Orissa help was impossible and it is said a million people
died. The Governments of India and Bengal had taken in effect no
precautions whatever.... I never could feel that I was free from all
blame for the result." Accordingly, he harbored a lifelong distrust of
officials who "worshipped political economy as a sort of `fetish'" as
well as Englishmen in India who accepted "famine as a salutary cure
for over-population." Yet, whatever his private misgivings, Salisbury
had urged appointment of the laissez-faire fanatic Lytton and publicly
congratulated Disraeli for repudiating "the growing idea that England
ought to pay tribute to India for having conquered her." Indeed, when
his own advisers later protested the repeal of cotton duties in the
face of the fiscal emergency of the famine, Salisbury denounced as a
"species of International Communism" the idea "that a rich Britain
should consent to penalize her trade for the sake of a poor India."
Like other architects of the Victorian Raj,
Salisbury was terrified of setting any precedent for the permanent
maintenance of the Indian poor. As the Calcutta Review pointed
out in 1877, "In India there is no legal provision made for the poor,
either in British territory, or in the native states; [although] the
need for it is said by medical men and others, to be exceedingly
great." Both Calcutta and London feared that "enthusiastic
prodigality" like Buckingham's would become a trojan horse for an
Indian Poor Law. In its final report, the Famine Commission of 1878-80
approvingly underscored Lord Lytton's skinflint reasoning: "The
doctrine that in time of famine the poor are entitled to demand relief
... would probably lead to the doctrine that they are entitled to such
relief at all times, and thus the foundation would be laid of a system
of general poor relief, which we cannot contemplate without serious
apprehension...." None of the principal players on either side of the
House of Commons disagreed with the supreme principle that India was
to be governed as a revenue plantation, not an almshouse.
The `Temple Wage'
Over the next year, the gathering horror of the drought-famine
spread from the Madras Presidency through Mysore, the Bombay Deccan
and eventually into the North Western Provinces. The crop losses in
many districts of the Deccan plateau and Tamilnad plains (see Table
1.2) were nothing short of catastrophic. Ryots in district
after district sold their "bullocks, field implements, the thatch of
the roofs, the frames of their doors and windows" to survive the
terrible first year of the drought. Without essential means of
production, however, they were unable to take advantage of the little
rain that fell in April-May 1877 to sow emergency crops of rape and
cumboo. As a result they died in their myriads in August and
September.
Millions more had reached the stage of acute
malnutrition, characterized by hunger edema and anemia, that modern
health workers call skeletonization. Village officers wrote to their
superiors from Nellore and other ravaged districts of the Madras
Deccan that the only well-fed part of the local population were the
pariah dogs, "fat as sheep," that feasted on the bodies of dead
children:
[A]fter a couple of minutes' search, I came upon two
dogs worrying over the body of a girl about eight years old. They
had newly attacked it, and had only torn one of the legs a little,
but the corpse was so enormously bloated that it was only from the
total length of the figure one could tell it was a child's. The
sight and smell of the locality were so revolting, and the dogs so
dangerous, that I did not stay to look for a second body; but I saw
two skulls and a backbone which had been freshly picked.
Officials, however, were not eager to share such horrors with the
English or educated Indian publics, and the vernacular press charged
that starvation deaths were being deliberately misreported as cholera
or dysentery mortality in order to disguise the true magnitude of the
famine.
Conditions were equally desperate across the
linguistic and administrative boundary in the Bombay Deccan. Almost
two-thirds of the harvest was lost in nine Maharashtran districts
affecting 8 million people, with virtually no crop at all in Sholapur
and Kaladgi. The disaster befell a peasantry already ground down by
exorbitant taxation and extortionate debt. In the Ahmednagar region
officials reported that no less than three-fifths of the peasantry was
"hopelessly indebted," while in Sholapur the district officer had
warned his superiors in May 1875: "I see no reason to doubt the fact
stated to me by many apparently trustworthy witnesses and which my own
personal observation confirms, that in many cases the assessments are
only paid by selling ornaments or cattle." (As Jairus Banaji comments,
"A household without cattle was a household on the verge of
extinction.") Ahmednagar with Poona had been the center of the famous
Deccan Riots in May-June 1875, when ryots beat up moneylenders and
destroyed debt records.
While British procrastination was sacrificing
charity to their savage god, the Invisible Hand, tens of thousands of
these destitute villagers were voting with their feet and fleeing to
Hyderabad, where the Nazim was providing assistance to famine victims.
A large part of Sholapur was depopulated before British officials
managed to organize relief works. Then, as a horrified British
journalist discovered, they turned away anyone who was too starved to
undertake hard coolie labor. But even "the labour test imposed upon
the able-bodied," the correspondent noted, "is found to be too heavy
for their famished frames; the wages paid are inadequately low; in
many districts all who are willing to work do not find employment....
No arrangements have been made to preserve the cattle by providing
fodder or pasture lands. No grain stores have been collected or
charity houses opened for the infirm and the aged." The only recourse
for the young, the infirm and the aged was therefore to attempt the
long trek to Hyderabad an ordeal that reportedly killed most of
them.
Widespread unemployment and the high price of
grain, meanwhile, brought the spectre of hunger even into districts
where rainfall had been adequate. As a result, several million
emaciated laborers and poor peasants overwhelmed the relief works
belatedly authorized by the Bombay and Madras governments. At the
beginning of February, the lieutenant-governor of Bengal, Sir Richard
Temple, was sent south as plenipotentiary Famine Delegate by Lytton to
clamp down on the "out of control" expenditures that threatened the
financing of the planned invasion of Afghanistan. Although the viceroy
had also skirmished bitterly with Sir Philip Wodehouse, the governor
of Bombay, over Calcutta's refusal to subsidize large-scale relief
works during the fall of 1876, his greatest indignation was directed
at Buckingham for making "public charity indiscriminate" in Bellary,
Cuddapah and Kurnool, where one-quarter of the population was employed
breaking stone or digging canals.
Temple was a shrewd choice as Lytton's enforcer.
Earlier, in 1873-74, he had followed Salisbury's urgings and dealt
aggressively with a drought that severely damaged the harvest
throughout most of Bengal and Bihar. Importing half a million tons of
rice from Burma, he provided life-saving subsistence, both through
relief works and a "gratuitous dole," which forestalled mass
mortality. Indeed, the official record claimed only twenty-three
starvation deaths. It was the only truly successful British relief
effort in the nineteenth century and might have been celebrated as a
template for dealing with future emergencies. Instead, Temple came
under withering fire from London for the "extravagance" of allowing
"the scale of wages paid at relief works to be determined by the daily
food needs of the labourer and the prevailing food prices in the
market rather than by the amount that the Government could afford to
spend for the purpose." In public, he was lambasted by The
Economist for encouraging indolent Indians to believe that "it is
the duty of the Government to keep them alive." Senior civil servants,
convinced (according to Lord Salisbury) that it was "a mistake to
spend so much money to save a lot of black fellows," denounced the
relief campaign as "pure Fourierism." Temple's career was almost
ruined.
In 1877 the thoroughly chastened
lieutenant-governor, "burning to retrieve his reputation for
extravagance in the last famine," had become the implacable instrument
of Lytton's frugality. The viceroy boasted to the India Office that he
could not have found "a man more likely, or better able to help us
save money in famine management." Indeed, The Times was soon
marveling at the "pliability" of his character: "Sir Richard Temple,
whether rightly or wrongly, has the reputation of having a mind so
plastic and principles so facile that he can in a moment change front
and adopt most contradictory lines of policy. His course in the famine
districts certainly seems to bear this out, for he is even more strict
than the Supreme Government in enforcing a policy which differs in
every respect from that which he himself practised in Behar three
years ago."
Although Victoria in her message to the Imperial
Assemblage had reassured Indians that their "happiness, prosperity and
welfare" were the "present aims and objects of Our Empire," Temple's
brief from the Council of India left no ambiguity about the
government's true priorities: "The task of saving life irrespective of
cost, is one which it is beyond our power to undertake. The
embarrassment of debt and weight of taxation consequent on the expense
thereby involved would soon become more fatal than the famine itself."
Likewise, the viceroy insisted that Temple everywhere in Madras
"tighten the reins." The famine campaign in Lytton's conception was a
semi-military demonstration of Britain's necessary guardianship over a
people unable to help themselves, not an opportunity for Indian
initiative or self-organization. If, as a modern authority on famine
emphasizes, "emergency relief, like development aid, is only truly
effective if the recipients have the power to determine what it is and
how it is used," Temple's perverse task was to make relief as
repugnant and ineffective as possible. In zealously following his
instructions to the letter, he became to Indian history what Charles
Edward Trevelyan permanent secretary to the Treasury during the
Great Hunger (and, later, governor of Madras) had become to Irish
history: the personification of free market economics as a mask for
colonial genocide.
In a lightning tour of the famished countryside
of the eastern Deccan, Temple purged a half million people from relief
work and forced Madras to follow Bombay's precedent of requiring
starving applicants to travel to dormitory camps outside their
locality for coolie labor on railroad and canal projects. The
deliberately cruel "distance test" refused work to able-bodied adults
and older children within a ten-mile radius of their homes. Famished
laborers were also prohibited from seeking relief until "it was
certified that they had become indigent, destitute and capable of only
a modicum of labour." Digby later observed that Temple "went to Madras
with the preconceived idea that the calamity had been exaggerated,
that it was being inadequately met, and that, therefore, facts were,
unconsciously may be, squared with this theory.... He expected to see
a certain state of things, and he saw that that and none other."
In a self-proclaimed Benthamite "experiment"
that eerily prefigured later Nazi research on minimal human
subsistence diets in concentration camps, Temple cut rations for male
coolies, whom he compared to "a school full of refractory children,"
down to one pound of rice per diem despite medical testimony that the
ryots once "strapping fine fellows" were now "little more than
animated skeletons ... utterly unfit for any work." (Noting that
felons traditionally received two pounds of rice per day, one district
official suggested that "it would be better to shoot down the wretches
than to prolong their misery in the way proposed.") The same reduced
ration had been introduced previously by General Kennedy (another
acerbic personality, "not personally popular even in his own
department") in the Bombay Deccan, and Madras's sanitary commissioner,
Dr. Cornish, was "of the opinion that `experiment' in that case
[meant] only slow, but certain starvation." Apart from its sheer
deficiency in energy, Cornish pointed out that the exclusive rice
ration without the daily addition of protein-rich pulses (dal),
fish or meat would lead to rapid degeneration. Indeed, as the
lieutenant-governor was undoubtedly aware, the Indian government had
previously fixed the minimum shipboard diet of emigrant coolies
"living in a state of quietude" at twenty ounces of rice plus one
pound of dal, mutton, vegetables and condiment. In the event, the
"Temple wage," as it became known, provided less sustenance for hard
labor than the diet inside the infamous Buchenwald concentration camp
and less than half of the modern caloric standard recommended for
adult males by the Indian government.
Temple, who three years earlier had fixed the
minimum ration during the Bengal famine at one and one-half pounds of
rice plus dal, now publicly disdained the protests of Cornish and
other medical officers. They erroneously, and "irresponsibly" in his
view, elevated public health above public finance. "Everything," he
lectured, "must be subordinated ... to the financial consideration of
disbursing the smallest sum of money consistent with the preservation
of human life." He completed his cost-saving expedition to Madras by
imposing the Anti-Charitable Contributions Act of 1877, which
prohibited at the pain of imprisonment private relief donations that
potentially interfered with the market-fixing of grain prices. He also
stopped Buckingham from remitting onerous land taxes in the famine
districts. In May, after Temple had reported back, the viceroy
censured Madras officials for their "exaggerated impressions" of
misery and "uncalled for relief." Temple meanwhile proclaimed that he
had put "the famine under control." (Digby sourly responded that "a
famine can scarcely be said to be adequately controlled which leaves
one-fourth of the people dead.")
The militarization of relief, followed by the
failure of the southwest monsoon and another doubling of grain prices
in the six months from the middle of 1877, punctually produced lethal
results. Exactly as medical officials had warned, the "Temple wage"
combined with heavy physical labor and dreadful sanitation turned the
work camps into extermination camps. By the end of May horrified
relief officials in Madras were reporting that more than half of the
inmates were too weakened to carry out any physical labor whatsoever.
Most of them were dead by the beginning of the terrible summer of
1877. As Temple's most dogged critic, Dr. Cornish, pointed out,
monthly mortality was now equivalent to an annual death rate of 94
percent. Post-mortem examinations, moreover, showed that the chief
cause of death "extreme wasting of tissue and destruction of the
lining membrane of the lower bowel" was textbook starvation, with
full-grown men reduced to under sixty pounds in weight. Mortality was
similar in camps throughout the Bombay Deccan, where cholera, spread
by polluted water and filth, accelerated the decimation. One official
wrote that one relief road project "bore the appearance of a
battlefield, its sides being strewn with the dead, the dying and those
recently attacked."
Jails ironically were the only exception to this
institutional mortality pattern, and they were generally preferred by
the poor to the disease-ridden relief camps. An American missionary
described how a group of weavers begged him to have them arrested for
nonfulfillment of a contract. "We are very sorry, sir, but we have
eaten up all the money you gave us, and we have made no clothes. We
are in a starving condition, and if you will only send us to jail we
shall get something to eat." It was an eminently sensible request.
"Prisoners were the best fed poor people in the country," and,
accordingly, "the jails were filled to overflowing."
During the Irish famine, Trevelyan had protested
that the country's "greatest evil" was not hunger, but "the selfish,
perverse and turbulent character of the people." Similarly, Temple's
ferocious response to reports of mass mortality in the camps was to
blame the victims: "The infatuation of these poor people in respect to
eating the bread of idleness; their dread of marching on command to
any distance from home; their preference often for extreme privation
rather than submission to even simple and reasonable orders, can be
fully believed only by those who have seen or personally known these
things." Moreover, he claimed that the majority of the famine dead
were not the cultivating yeomanry, "the bone and sinew of the
country," but parasitic mendicants who essentially had committed
suicide: "Nor will many be inclined to grieve much for the fate which
they brought upon themselves, and which terminated lives of idleness
and too often of crime."
(Continues...)
(C) 2001 Mike Davis All rights reserved. ISBN:
1-85984-739-0